Comment by testrun

Comment by testrun 2 days ago

16 replies

A few counter examples:

1. TSMC (supported by the ROC government[https://dominotheory.com/tsmc-and-taiwans-government-two-boa...])

2. Korean chaebols (Samsung, Hyundai, LG etc, supported by ROK government[https://www.investopedia.com/terms/c/chaebol-structure.asp])

3. Japanese heavy industries (Japanese government support)

The government support are a combination of low interest loans, import controls and financial subsidies.

eru 2 days ago

That the favoured industry (or company) is doing well isn't necessarily a sign that the policy is overall good for the country's economy.

As an analogy: weapons manufacturers do well when there's a war on, too, but that doesn't mean war is good for prosperity.

  • smallnamespace 2 days ago

    > That the favoured industry (or company) is doing well isn't necessarily a sign that the policy is overall good for the country's economy.

    You are answering specifics with generalities.

    If Taiwan didn't support and nurture TSMC so that today it's a national champion that prints money, what development path do you think they could have taken that would've brought at least the same economic success? Please be specific.

    • eru 2 days ago

      There's plenty of other companies in Taiwan already today, and that's without the counterfactual of leaving more money in people's hands.

      I can't predict specifically what other things would have happened. If people could do these kinds of predictions well, maybe central planning would actually work?

      • smallnamespace a day ago

        You are saying planning never works without even the ability to point to any specific cases. Why do you swallow your own ideology so uncritically?

        Does Soviet-style central planning work? It didn't seem to work well in the few societies that really tried it.

        Dos all planning fail? Seems unlikely, given the amount of fairly centralized planning that went on (and still goes on today) in East Asian countries, countries that are the rare "success stories" of developmental economics.

        In fact the original East Asian success story was Meiji-era Japan, basically the only society outside of the West that managed to industrialize itself during the 19th century. And if one sits down to read a history book one quickly realizes that what the Meiji government did was highly top-down and planned with the explicit goal to catch up to the European colonial powers. It did not resemble classical laissez-faire economics.

throw0101a 2 days ago

> The government support are a combination of low interest loans, import controls and financial subsidies.

There is a very well-understood formula on how to go for from an agrarian society to an industrial one, which has been used going back to the late 1800s:

* https://www.goodreads.com/book/show/16144575-how-asia-works

Of course you have to actually follow it, and not get sidetracked with cronyism and such, like the Philippines did:

* https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Crony_capitalism

  • eru 2 days ago

    'How Asia Works' is not exactly economic orthodoxy, to put it lightly.

    • chlodwig 2 days ago

      Is that an indictment of the book or of economic orthodoxy?

    • epistasis 2 days ago

      I would like to hear how that book is viewed by the orthodoxy, if you have any pointers.

    • throw0101a 2 days ago

      > 'How Asia Works' is not exactly economic orthodoxy, to put it lightly.

      And yet it describes the historical record of several countries (in the case of Japan, how they did it twice: post-Meiji Restoration and post-WW2).

      It goes over countries deemed 'successful' (Japan, Korea, etc), and others (Philippines).

      What (particular?) "economic orthodoxy" would you suggest countries follow? What are countries (if any) have followed them, and what are the results? Are there book(s) that you would recommend on how to implement this/these orthodoxies, with case studies or historical examples of implementations?

      • eru 6 hours ago

        'How Asia works' describes the historical record of some examples, yes.

        There are some correlations between various factors and 'success'. Alas, it's hard to tease out which of the correlations, if any, are causal factors, and which are just coincidences, or worse. [0]

        The book guesses at some of these causal factors, and makes policy recommendations.

        I am mostly not really convinced by the full list of causal factors the book presents. On the one hand, the book observes protectionism and argues that it's a causal factor in promoting prosperity. That's just the old and tired 'Infant Industry Argument', so we should require quite some evidence to take it serious. On the other hand, the book ignores the possible impact of having lots of ethnically Chinese people in your country. (I don't know for sure whether that's a causal factor, but it sure looks noteworthy and deserves at least as much consideration and discussion any of the other factors.)

        I also think the book is too quick to dismiss Hong Kong and especially Singapore. Singapore did not start out as a financial centre, and especially early on manufacturing was much more important here.

        > What (particular?) "economic orthodoxy" would you suggest countries follow?

        Much of what the successful countries examined in the book have been doing is worth following.

        In any case, if you want an orthodox policy recommendation: the Washington Consensus was pretty decent. Lots of examples there.

        Well, to be precise: Washington Consensus with the crucial addition that your central bank (if you have one) should be doing something like nominal GDP level targeting.

        What that means is that the total nominal spending in your economy needs to be on a stable path. Don't let it grow too much, or you get inflation and overheat the economy. Don't let it collapse, or you get a recession.

        See Scott Sumner's or George Selgin's writing for why that's really important and how that can work. (And why it's more sensible than targeting inflation.)

        As a cautionary tale, look at Argentina. They were doing fairly well during their neoliberal / Washington consensus phase, but their currency arrangements led to a collapse of aggregate nominal spending in the economy. Alas, the subsequent recession was blamed on neoliberalism.

        For examples with stable total spending, have a look at Israel or Australia. (At least until a few years ago, I haven't checked recently.) Both countries' nominal stability let them avoid recessions. Australia is especially noteworthy, because as a resource exporter you'd expect their economic fortunes to be as volatile as commodity prices. See https://marketmonetarist.com/2012/11/19/the-export-price-nor... for an investigation.

        https://www.amazon.com/Just-Get-Out-Way-Government/dp/193086... is an alternative view at development economics. The title is a bit provocative, (even the author wasn't really happy with it, when I had a chat with him about it). The main thesis of the book is that honest and competent civil servants are the most rare and precious resource a country has, especially a poor one, so policies should economies on their labour.

        So eg you should privatise a state-owned company by auctioning it off in one piece to the highest cash-bidder open to all comers from anywhere, no questions asked. Instead of having your civil servants set up a complex system or worse trying to evaluate proposed business plans. Complexity breeds corruption in the worst case, and in the best case still takes up civil servants' limited time.

        See also https://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/GermanEconomicMiracle.ht... for some recommendations.

        [0] When I say 'worse', I have in mind an example like: empirically we can observe a strong correlation between personal wealth and owning a fancy car. Alas, that doesn't mean getting yourself a fancy car will make you rich. Just the opposite, in fact.